More on the New Party List Decision
Joaquin G. Bernas, S.J.
The controversial party-list cases have been remanded by the Supreme
Court to the Comelec for review.
What the Comelec is required to do is to decide two related
questions: (1) Which organizations
may participate in the party list system?
(2) Who are qualified to represent the party list organizations?
My column last week was an attempt to answer the first of the above
questions. Let me summarize. (a) The inspiration of the system is
social justice understood in both the economic and political sense. (b) Participation in the system is not
limited to the sectors enumerated by the Constitution or law, i.e., “labor,
peasant, urban poor, indigenous cultural communities, women, youth, and such
other sectors as may be provided by law.”
(c) The enumerated sectors must be economically marginalized because
that is what disables them from successfully engaging in the political struggle. (d) The national and regional
organizations need not be economically marginalized but they must be
politically or ideologically disadvantaged or marginalized. (e) Traditional political parties, if
they wish to participate, must renounce participation in district elections. (f) Segments of political parties, if
they wish to participate, must be separately incorporated and be independent of
their original parties.
In all of this, the Comelec must be guided by what the Supreme Court has
said about the common denominator of participating organizations, namely: “The
common denominator between sectoral and non-sectoral parties is that they
cannot expect to win in legislative district elections but they can garner, in nationwide
elections, at least the same number of votes that winning candidates can garner
in legislative district elections.
The party-list system will be the entry point to membership in the House of Representatives for both these
non-traditional parties that could not compete in legislative district
elections.”
And that is the difficult part causing concern, because it involves the
evaluation of difficult factual issues.
It is relatively easy to determine whether a sectoral party, e.g., of
security guards, is economically marginalized and underrepresented and thus
does not have much of a chance to win in a district election. But if the security guards of the
country band together they might win one of the seats in the 20% share of party
list organizations. The same would
be the case of other sectoral parties or a combination of them. But how does one measure the strength
of non=traditional or regional parties?
The concern of some, however, is that non-traditional national or
regional parties might guzzle up all of the 20% share of party-list
organizations if the non-sectorals happen to have the support of moneyed
individuals. Realistically, however, where are these non-traditional
parties who are so vote rich and
so economically affluent as to be able to wipe out the economically marginalized
and underrepresented?
The point is that the party list system was designed for groups that “cannot
expect to win in legislative district elections but can garner, in nationwide elections, at least the same
number of votes that winning candidates can garner in legislative district
elections.” These are the
disadvantaged who wish to win but cannot win representation through district
elections. They are the
beneficiaries of social justice in the 1987 Constitution which favors those who
have less in life either economically or politically.
Pluralism is a characteristic of a democracy. “To require all national
and regional parties under the party-list system to represent the ‘marginalized
and underrepresented’ is to deprive and exclude, by judicial fiat,
ideology-based and cause-oriented parties from the party-list system. How will
these ideology-based and cause-oriented parties, who cannot win in legislative
district elections, participate in the electoral process if they are excluded
from the party-list system? To exclude them from the party- list system is to
prevent them from joining the parliamentary struggle, leaving as their only
option the armed struggle.”
Moreover, I repeat my question: Where are the wealthy national or
regional organizations capable of burying the sectors under an avalanche of
votes? Will the Comelec be able to
uncover them?
I now come to the qualifications of a party-list representative. This is a relatively easier puzzle for
the Comelec. A party-list
representative, of course, must have the qualifications of a district
representative except for the residence requirement because he or she does not
represent a district. But one must
be a bona fide member of the party or organization which one seeks to represent
at least 90 days before the election. In the case of sectoral parties, to be a
bona fide party-list representative one must either belong to the sector
represented, or have a track record of advocacy for such sector. In other words, to represent a party of
farmers, one need not be a farmer but must have a track record of advocacy for
such sector.
Ultimately, however, let us remember that the party-list system was meant
to be an experiment. Next time we
review the Constitution, let us take a good hard look at the results of the experiment.
22 April 2013
Take away the PDAF and let us see if there will still be shameless opportunist trying to sneak in the backdoor of the legislative process......
ReplyDelete